Friday, December 16, 2011
The International Monetary Fund and Nepal
The International Financial Institutions Advisory Commission’s report
in 2003 suggested that the International Monetary Fund’s system of short-term
crisis management was “too costly… responses too slow… advice often incorrect…
and efforts to influence policy and practice too intrusive”. That was one of
the first reports to come out about international aid organizations like the
IMF and the World Bank’s effectiveness, or lack thereof, in helping poor
nations. That and several other reports that have come out in the past few
years have asked pertinent questions: Is the IMF doing any good? Is it being
faithful to its core customers or to its core donors? Is it perpetuating the
western dominance in the eastern and African countries?
For those that are unaware, the IMF is like a bank that gives money to
countries that need them. Like normal people, countries also go into debt that
they, sometimes, cannot pay. During such times, like normal people, the
countries are not able to get credit from lenders due to their previous
default. During such times, the IMF acts as a lender of last resort albeit with
some conditions applied. The applied condition, about 99 percent of the time,
is an immediate restructuring of the borrower country’s economy through IMF’s
macroeconomic stabilization policies.
The IMF carries out its macroeconomic stabilization policies in four
basic steps. First, the borrowing country must abolish or liberalize the
foreign exchange and import controls. Second, the official exchange rate of the
borrower is devalued. Third, the borrower must open up its economy and accept
FDI inflows. And, fourth, the borrower must accept IMF’s strong anti-inflation
program.
These steps look innocuous. So, why do countries always oppose IMF’s
policies and programs? Well, the main reason is because IMF acts and imposes
these programs like a schoolyard bully. Time and again evidences arise that
showcase its heavy handedness in dealing with poor countries that are meek and
have no voice. Yet, at the same time, it can do nothing to the heavy donors
that “fund” the Fund.
For instance, when the financial crisis hit the world in 2008, the G20
summit in London in the first week of April 2009 came up with a plan to give
$750 billion to the IMF in order to rescue any country in the world hit the
hardest by that crisis. However, by the end of April, only Japan had given its
share of $100 billion to the IMF. The promises made by other rich countries
turned out to be hollow. This is, but, only one example. The IMF has been
unable to rein its richer ponies.
Also, no matter what the cause of any macroeconomic problem in a
country in any corner of the world, the IMF’s most common solution is to ask
countries to reduce inflation. The Fund has to realize that all diseases do not
have the same cure. Macroeconomic conditions and problems in different
countries are diverse and varied. For an organization that boasts of many
eminent scholars, researchers and bureaucrats, the IMF’s repeated inflationary stance
makes it look like a one-trick pony.
Reducing inflation does not solve all systemic macroeconomic problems. You
need inflation to achieve economic growth. If inflation really hampered
macroeconomic stability and economic growth to the extent that the IMF policymakers
think, why are high inflation countries like India, China, and Bangladesh
achieving almost double digit economic growth while low inflation countries in
Europe along with Japan and the United States growing below 3 percent?
And, why is it that it is always the poorer countries that are asked to
restructure their economy? IMF says that restructuring is a pre-condition to
the assistance being given. Why are such pre-conditions not applied when the
richer countries borrow from IMF? If restructuring is a pre-condition to the
assistance, then why is the United States, the world’s largest debtor, never
asked to restructure its economy? Why is Italy or France not asked to
restructure its economy when it borrows?
And, then, there’s the issue of transparency. Noted scholars like Jeffrey
Sachs have mentioned that for an organization that touts itself as a watchdog, and
one that asks for openness from its clients, the IMF is very secretive. Independent
observers claim impossibility in performing a serious appraisal of IMF programs
and policies. This is unlike the World Bank, which produces diligent and honest
assessment of its own programs and policies. The World Bank’s own assessment of
its African performance suggested a 73 percent failure rate. When was the last
time that anything like that was heard from the IMF camp? What I am asking is:
Who watches the watchdog?
During the aftermath of the financial crisis, the IMF was very flexible
to the European countries that asked for emergency loans to survive the crisis.
Yet, it spared no mercy to Pakistan, Bangladesh and the African countries. They
were still asked to cut their spending even though they were going through the
same crisis as their European counterparts. Therefore, the IMF has a
double-standard when it comes to applying its pre-conditions. And, that’s not
fair. If the rules do not apply equally to all the players in the game, I don’t
want my country playing that game.
Subscribe to Posts [Atom]
Post a Comment